Support us
Share
  • Published: Jan 25 2024
  • 12 minute read

About the Author

Ruth Bloch Rubin is a professor in the Department of Political Science. Her research explores how intraparty divisions drive patterns of lawmaking, institutional development, and party leadership in Congress. She is the author of Building the Bloc: Intraparty Organization in the U.S. Congress (Cambridge University Press), which explains the logic and development of organized intraparty factions in the first branch. Building the Bloc was awarded the Alan Rosenthal Prize by APSA's Legislative Studies Section for the best article or book by a junior scholar and the D.B. Hardeman Prize by the Lyndon Baines Johnson Foundation for the best book on Congress by a biographer, historian, journalist, or political scientist.

Summary

Promise of the Reform

"Many important and popular pieces of legislation that have majority support are not enacted because their sponsors lack the votes to override a potential Senate filibuster. By changing how the filibuster is practiced, or eliminating it altogether, the Senate would no longer be hostage to relentless obstruction and would instead be more productive and responsive to the will of the people."

Key Takeaways from the Research

  • Filibustering has become more common in recent decades.

  • The filibuster is often characterized as anti-majoritarian, but Senate majorities have the power to change the practice and have mostly opted not to.

  • The filibuster is not the only or most important source of legislative gridlock. The most common reason Senate majorities fail to enact their agendas is internal disagreement.

  • Issue-specific carveouts, including special rules and a majoritarian budget process, make it possible for a motivated majority to legislate in the absence of a supermajority.

  • Without the filibuster, power would likely become more centralized in majority and minority party leadership.

Important Questions that the Research Does Not Answer

  • Who benefits most from the filibuster: members of the minority party or majority party members closest to the floor median?

  • Would the Senate really be more responsive or productive if the filibuster were eliminated (or its use sharply curtailed)?

  • How would inter-cameral and inter-branch politics change if the filibuster were curbed?

Introduction

"Obstructionism in the modern Senate 'is woven into the fabric of things."

It’s easy to understand why many people want to reform the Senate filibuster.

While the era of the talking filibuster — the lengthy speeches intended to delay a floor vote — has long since passed, today, simply the threat of obstruction (a “silent” filibuster or “hold” on a nomination) is sufficient to compel Senate leaders to move on to new business.1 As a result, the incidence of filibustering (both real and threatened) has increased significantly,2 leading some observers to suggest that obstructionism in the modern Senate “is woven into the fabric of things.”3 Proponents of reform, often progressives, point out that Senate Rule XXII, which requires a 60-vote supermajority to close debate, is incompatible with the principle of majority rule. How can it be right, reform proponents argue, that 40 senators representing states with dwindling populations can use procedural means to frustrate the will of the majority of Americans? These concerns aren’t simply hypothetical. In practice, the filibuster has been employed to support repugnant positions. It was used in the nineteenth century to protest federal oversight of elections in the former Confederacy and again in the mid-twentieth century to prevent passage of anti-lynching, anti-poll tax, and civil rights bills.4 Finally, the filibuster is thought to disproportionately benefit Republicans, who have a narrow legislative agenda and possess a range of other legislative tools to defeat policy interventions they oppose.

In contrast, friends of the filibuster argue that it provides political minorities a voice in an otherwise ruthlessly majoritarian legislative process. Or they contend that, by slowing the pace of lawmaking, Senators are incentivized to deliberate and find consensus.5

Broadly speaking, filibuster reform efforts have centered on four proposals:

  • Getting rid of the filibuster altogether, as was done with the House filibuster in the 1880s.

  • Returning to the “talking” filibuster or reducing the number of senators needed to secure cloture to end debate.

  • Further narrowing what can be subject to a filibuster, adding new carveouts to the current menu of judicial nominations and budget bills.

  • Reimagining who gets to filibuster, such that, perhaps only senators representing states that in combination constitute a majority of the population ought to have the privilege.6

This primer has two aims. First, to understand the particular appeal of filibuster reform today, and, second, to assess whether making it more difficult to engage in strategic delay would render the Senate more productive and responsive to public opinion.

Theoretical Research on the Filibuster

"For those who oppose the filibuster, sensitivity to minority interests is a problem."

To understand why a behavior that frustrates so many has lasted so long, it is helpful to ask: what purpose does the filibuster serve?

The filibuster protects minority rights. If a minority of senators prefer the status quo to a proposed change, they can use the filibuster to forestall action and potentially preserve their favored equilibrium.7 For the filibuster’s defenders, this is a good thing. The bills that pass the Senate via regular procedure will have the backing of a legislative supermajority and, at least in theory, the support of most Americans.

For those who oppose the filibuster, sensitivity to minority interests is a problem. Majorities are elected with a mandate to govern and the minority party shouldn’t get to make that task more difficult. The Senate filibuster is an unnecessary obstacle to enacting policies that are popular with voters and central to the majority party’s agenda.

The Senate filibuster is unusual among allegedly anti-majoritarian legislative procedures for its durability (consider that the House filibuster was phased out in the late nineteenth century).

This has led some to suggest that the filibuster is not anti-majoritarian at all, but actually reflects the preferences of successive Senate majorities. In recent decades, for instance, both Democratic and Republican majorities have created filibuster carveouts to advance judicial nominees.8

The filibuster provides information. Uncertainty is endemic to the legislative process. Not only must a legislator ascertain who supports (or opposes) a bill she wishes to pass, and who is likely to vote for it (or against it), she must also gauge how intensely those preferences are held. The more intense the opposition, the harder the sponsor will have to work to get her bill enacted.9 (A related claim for which there is little evidence, but much insistence, is that filibustering prolongs substantive debate over a policy’s particulars, thus improving information about the policy itself.)

Filibustering conveys credible information to the Senate about how determined a senator is to maintain the status quo and/or the relative reward she derives from fighting.10 After all, senators have lots of things to do other than filibuster, and so their choice to filibuster suggests they really care about the issue. But the less costly it is for any senator (or group of senators) to filibuster, the noisier the signal about the intensity of their opposition. If filibustering is cheap and easy, there is little to stop lawmakers from filibustering on issues they care only weakly about.

"To the extent we believe leaders are good at their jobs, the filibuster may not add much to their toolkit."

The filibuster helps leaders agenda-set efficiently. Given that time is scarce, and policy-making hard, the Senate cannot legislate on everything. At the same time, because filibustering requires an outlay of time and/or political capital, senators will be selective in what they choose to obstruct, presumably opposing only those bills they dislike the most. Senate leaders can use the presence (or absence) of a filibuster to distinguish between those bills that are likely to have strong, bipartisan support and those that are likely to generate meaningful opposition.11 By putting those bills that lack a filibuster threat on the agenda, the Senate can prioritize mutually agreeable policy interventions and legislate more efficiency. But, here too, the filibuster promotes efficiency only if filibustering is somewhat costly and Senate leaders are otherwise unable to identify bills with cross-party appeal. To the extent we believe leaders are good at their jobs, the filibuster may not add much to their toolkit.

The filibuster serves senators’ reelection goals. Legislating is a collective enterprise, but lawmakers are elected on their own auspices. This means that legislators will always be on the hunt for ways to distinguish themselves or score points with their constituents.12 This dynamic has led some to theorize that filibustering, independent of its outcome, carries political rewards. Even quixotic efforts to obstruct the legislative process provide opportunities for a senator to credibly signal to donors or constituents her position on (or commitment to) an issue.13 Consider, for example, that both Texas’s Ted Cruz and Kentucky’s Rand Paul increased their public profiles through regular (if ultimately fruitless) obstruction.

Empirical Research on the Filibuster

"Throughout the Senate’s history, threatened rules changes restrained minority obstruction."

What, if any, evidence do we have that the filibuster is about more than minoritarian obstruction?

The procedures filibustering senators draw on are not necessarily minoritarian. As only fifty-one senators are needed to change the chamber rules that make filibustering possible, filibusterers operate with the tacit consent of the Senate majority. Notably, majority-party senators near the floor median have consistently defended dilatory procedures, suggesting that a legislative majority (if not the majority party) backs the practice.

Accordingly, if the filibuster were routinely serving the interests of only a minority of the Senate, a sufficiently motivated majority could alter their use.14 Indeed, throughout the Senate’s history, threatened rules changes restrained minority obstruction. In this sense, the filibuster reflects “remote majoritarianism.”15

The majority party has circumvented the filibuster when it has wanted to. Reforms to the congressional budget process and a host of associated special rules (also known as “majoritarian exceptions”) aid Senate majorities in exploiting issue-specific carveouts for the filibuster. Thanks to exceptions like the “Byrd rule,” senators can use the budget process to pass any legislative package that has a substantial budgetary component by a simple majority. So, too, the Senate has adopted rules changes that insulate judicial nominees from the filibuster.

"The use of majoritarian exceptions has declined, while the number of threatened filibusters has only grown."

In theory, these issue-specific carveouts make it possible for Senate majorities to work around the filibuster should they wish to.16 In practice, however, the use of majoritarian exceptions has declined, while the number of threatened filibusters has only grown. One way to interpret these trends is to say that, given the costs of using special rules to bypass a filibuster, majorities will do so only when members are sufficiently motivated to change the status quo. Put differently, filibusters tend to be threatened over bills that majorities are lukewarm about or where they cannot reach consensus.

Conclusion

"There is little evidence that any of the proposed filibuster reforms would significantly improve the Senate’s productivity and responsiveness to public opinion."

The filibuster surely makes it harder for the Senate to legislate, but it seems that the extent to which the practice contributes to gridlock or yields anti-majoritarian outcomes has been exaggerated. The real obstacle to legislating in the Senate appears, in fact, to be senators themselves.

There is little evidence that filibuster reform would significantly improve the Senate’s productivity and responsiveness to public opinion.17 Political scientists have instead found that the most common reason majority parties fail to enact their agendas is internal disagreement.18

Notwithstanding the possibility that polarization has encouraged Senate minorities to engage in obstruction, threats to filibuster do not account for a greater share of majority-party agenda failures in recent legislative sessions.19 The upshot is that reformers interested in increasing the Senate’s productivity might be better served finding other targets.

If the productivity argument fails, what about the role of the filibuster in determining the Senate’s overall responsiveness? Were the filibuster to be removed, would the upper chamber better reflect majoritarian interests? By definition, if the Senate were to operate by majoritarian rules, its legislative output would reflect the preferences of a chamber majority. However, majority rule in Congress has generally redounded to the benefit of the majority party as a whole, rather than to its individual members.

Within legislative parties, authority tends to be distributed hierarchically, and rank-and-file members possess substantially less power than their leadership.

This is thought to benefit the party collectively, as it can coordinate more efficiently and thereby create a public reputation for effectiveness.20 For that reason, majoritarian reforms, including the elimination of the lower-chamber’s filibuster, are often accompanied by procedural changes that centralize power in party leadership and disempower rank-and-file members.21 Were the filibuster weakened or eliminated, it would likely continue to trend towards centralizing power in the majority party and its leadership.22

In summary, it maybe that, despite the principled objections to the filibuster and despite its inglorious historical use, its abolition wouldn’t necessarily deliver the benefits that reformers desire.

Endnotes

1 Fisk, Catherine and Chemerinsky, Erwin “The Filibuster,” Stanford Law Review, 49 (1997): 181-254

2 Bell, Lauren, Filibustering in the U.S. Senate (Amherst, MA: Cambria Press, 2011) Binder, Sarah, Lawrence, Eric D. and Smith, Steven, “Tracking the Filibuster, 1917 to 1996,” American Politics Research, 30:4 (2002): 406-422

3 Evans, Larry and Lapinski, Daniel, “Leadership and Obstructionism in the U.S. Senate,” Congress Reconsidered, 8th ed. (Washington, D.C.: CQ Press, 2005)

4 Jentleson, Adam, Kill Switch: The Rise of the Modern Senate and the Crippling of American Democracy (New York: Liveright Publishing Corporation, 2021)

Litt, David, “The Senate Filibuster is Another Monument to White Supremacy: Tear it Down,” The Atlantic, June 2020, https://www.theatlantic.com/ideas/archive/2020/06/senate-filibuster-monumentwhite-supremacy/613579/

Wirls, Daniel, The Senate: From White Supremacy to Government Gridlock (Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press, 2021)

5 Arenberg, Richard and Dove, Robert, Defending the Filibuster: The Soul of the Senate (Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press, 2012)

6 Gould, Jonathan S., Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Stephenson, Matthew C., “Democratizing the Senate from Within,” Journal of Legal Analysis 13 (2021): 502-557

7 Eidelson, Benjamin, “The Majoritarian Filibuster,” Yale Law Journal 122:4 (2013): 852-1103 Krehbiel, Keith, Pivotal Politics: A Theory of U.S. Lawmaking (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1998)

8 Binder, Sarah A., Madonna, Anthony J. and Smith, Steven S., “Going Nuclear, Senate Style,” Perspectives on Politics 5:4 (2007): 729-740 Wawro, Gregory J. and Schickler, Eric, Filibuster: Obstruction and Lawmaking in the U.S. Senate (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2006)

9 Fu, Shu and Howell, William G., “The Filibuster and Legislative Discourse,” Journal of Politics (forthcoming).

10 Burdette, Franklin L., Filibustering in the Senate (New York: Russell & Russell, 1940)

Dion, Douglas, Boehmke, Frederick J., MacMillan, William and Shipan, Charles R. “The Filibuster as a War of Attrition,” Journal of Law and Economics, 59:1 (2016): 569-595

Wawro, Gregory J. and Schickler, Eric, Filibuster: Obstruction and Lawmaking in the U.S. Senate (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2006)

11 Fong, Christian and Krehbiel, Keith, “Limited Obstruction,” American Political Science Review, 112:1 (2018): 1-14

12 Mayhew, David, Congress: The Electoral Connection (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1974), 141

13 Koger, Gregory, Filibustering: A Political History of Obstruction in the House and Senate (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2010)

Patty, John W., “Signaling through Obstruction,” American Journal of Political Science 60:1 (2016): 175-189

14 Judd, Gleason and Rothenberg, Lawrence S., “The Waning and Stability of the Filibuster,” February 12, 2021, unpublished manuscript https://gleasonjudd. princeton.edu/sites/g/files/toruqf5246/files/gjudd/files/filibuster.pdf

15 Wawro, Gregory J. and Schickler, Eric, Filibuster: Obstruction and Lawmaking in the U.S. Senate (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2006)

16 Reynolds, Molly E., Exceptions to the Rules: The Politics of Filibuster Limitations in the U.S. Senate (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, 2017)

17 Ramey, Adam, “Filibusted? The Mixed Effects of ‘Going Nuclear,’” November 4, 2017). https://ssrn.com/abstract=3065237 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3065237

18 Curry, James M. and Lee, Frances E., The Limits of Party: Congress and Lawmaking in a Polarized Era (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2020)

19 Curry, James M. and Lee, Frances E., “One Obstacle Among Many: The Filibuster and Majority Party Agendas,” The Forum 19:4 (2021): 685-708

20 Cox, Gary W. and McCubbins, Mathew D., Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1993)

21 Jenkins, Jeffery A. and Stewart, Charles, Fighting for the Speakership: The House and the Rise of Party Government (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2012)

22 Binder, Sarah, “Marching (Senate Style) Towards Majority Rule,” The Forum 19:4 (2021): 663-684

About the Democracy Reform Primer Series

Narrowing the gap between research and public dialogue, the University of Chicago Center for Effective Government's Democracy Reform Primers responsibly advance conversations and strategy about proposed changes to our political institutions. Each Primer focuses on a particular reform, clarifies its intended purposes, and critically evaluates what the best available research has to say about it. The Primers do not serve as a platform for either authors or the Center to advance their own independent views about the reform; to the contrary, they serve as an objective and authoritative guide about what we actually know—and what we still don’t know—about the likely effects of adopting prominent reforms to our political institutions.

In some instances, the available evidence may clearly support the claims of a reform’s advocates. In other instances, it may cut against them. And in still others, the scholarly literature may be mixed, indeterminate, or altogether silent. Without partisan judgment or ideological pretense, and grounded in objective scholarship, these Primers set the record straight by clarifying what can be said about democracy reforms with confidence and what requires further study. This series is produced with support from Democracy Fund and the Democracy Innovation Fund.

About the Series Editor

Anthony Fowler is a Professor at the Harris School of Public Policy at the University of Chicago. His research applies econometric methods for causal inference to questions in political science, with particular emphasis on elections and political representation. Fowler is currently the Co-editor in Chief of the Quarterly Journal of Political Science, and the co-author (with Ethan Bueno de Mesquita) of Thinking Clearly with Data: A Guide to Quantitative Reasoning and Analysis (Princeton University Press, 2021). Fowler earned his Ph.D. in government from Harvard University and completed undergraduate studies at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology.